Research
Are All Sovereign Defaults
Strategic? (revised October, 2022)
The Greek default crisis does not fit stylized facts for strategic default. We extend the strategic default model to allow excusable and strategic default. We replace the assumption that default exit is random and costless with the assumption that exit can be chosen any time with payment of recovery value. Recovery is determined by ability to pay, consistent with IMF guidelines that a defaulting sovereign negotiate "in good faith," reducing debt to something "sustainable." Payment of recovery is excusable default, whereas non-payment is strategic. The extended model matches behavior leading to the Greek crisis and identifies it as excusable.
The Greek Crisis:
Strategic vs Excusable Default (Journal of International Economics, September, 2022) co-authored with Jinwook Nam
The Greek debt crisis revealed that sovereign default is not limited to emerging and developing countries. Can we take the strategic default model, developed for emerging markets, and recalibrate it to explain the crisis in Greece? The Greek economy differs from an emerging market in having higher government debt relative to GDP, counter-cyclical government debt, and consumption smoother than income. Our recalibrated strategic default model matches the high debt/GDP, but it misses the other two features of advanced countries. And it fails to generate a crisis. We propose an alternative model, replacing the absence of commitment to repay with commitment. Default occurs due to inability to repay and is excusable. Our alternative model of excusable default allows us to match the behavior of debt and the spread as the crisis approaches, as well as key features of business cycles in advanced countries. It also generates a crisis with correct timing.
Sovereign Default in
a Rich Country (revised July, 2019)
Rising debt following the Great Recession climaxed in the Greek debt crisis. Yet, this crisis did not evolve as a typical strategic default crisis. Debt/GDP reached levels much higher than could be supported by standard costs to default. Debt was countercyclical in the decade prior to the crisis. As the crisis approached, debt spiked, instead of falling. We argue that a rich-country sovereign faces different incentives for default, which alter debt dynamics. We modify the strategic default model to have a reputational equilibrium by introducing multiple contracts with spillovers in value. Default occurs only due to inability to repay and is excusable if the sovereign repays what she is able. We calibrate to the 2010 Greek crisis, and demonstrate that the rich-country default model allows much larger values for debt/GDP than strategic default and matches Greek debt dynamics prior to the crisis. We use the calibrated model to explain crisis severity, including magnitudes for endogenous risk premia, haircuts, and default duration.
Identifying
Countries at Risk of Fiscal Crises: High-Debt Developed Countries (Canadian
Journal of Economics, May, 2022)
co-authored with Christos Shiamptanis
Crises in European countries
in 2010 and beyond demonstrated that fiscal crises and sovereign default are
not confined to emerging and developing countries. Advanced economies can
sustain much larger debt-to-GDP ratios than emerging economies, but how much
larger? Experience is heterogeneous both across countries and across time. What
determines this heterogeneity? We show that a low growth-adjusted interest
rate, a large maximum value for the primary surplus, and a strong
surplus-responsiveness to debt can support higher debt-to-GDP ratios without
fiscal crisis. We use our estimates to assess fiscal crisis risk for
nine-high-debt developed countries following the financial crisis in 2008. Our
results imply that Ireland and Portugal lost access to financial markets due to
the rise in growth-adjusted interest rate, whereas Greece would have lost
access regardless of the interest rate. Additionally, our results warn of
potential future crises for Greece, Italy and Japan even if these countries
remain in a low interest rate environment.
Asymmetries in Business
Cycles and the Role of Oil Production (Macroeconomic
Dynamics June, 2019) co-authored with Christian M.
Hafner, Hans Manner, and Leopold Simar
Taylor-Rule Exit Policies for the Zero Lower Bound (International Journal of Central Banking, December, 2018) co-authored with Siddhartha Chattopadhyay
A country participating in a monetary union is constrained by loss of
control over seigniorage revenue. Once the government reaches its fiscal limit
on ordinary taxation, it cannot turn to seigniorage for financing. We show that
a monetary union country can increase its seigniorage revenue by reissuing its
own currency even as it fully honors all outstanding debt obligations. We use a
simple cash-in-advance model, with domestic currency demand motivated by the
need to pay taxes, to show that this policy effectively redistributes
seigniorage revenue away from other monetary union members toward the acting
country. The magnitude of the seigniorage created by currency reissue is
limited both by the relative size of the country and by money demand, and,
therefore, by the tax base. If this seigniorage revenue is insufficient, some
additional seigniorage is available by allowing the new currency to grow and
depreciate over time and domestic real wages to fall.
We present a dynamic and quantitative model
of a fiscal solvency crisis in a monetary union. Diverse fiscal policies, which
are subject to fiscal limits and stochastic shocks, can threaten a monetary
union. The fiscal limits arise due to distortionary taxation and political
will. Stochastic shocks are random and could push a fiscally sound policy towards
its limit. In equilibrium agents refuse to lend along a path which violates the
fiscal limits, creating a fiscal solvency crisis. The dynamics leading to the
crisis depend on the policy response to restore lending. We focus on two
responses, default and policy switching. We simulate our model to quantify the
probability of a fiscal solvency crisis in the European Monetary Union with
fiscal variables at end of 2009 values. Our model predicts the Greek crisis
which occurred and warns of an Italian one.
Private-Sector Risk and
Financial Crises in Emerging Markets (slides) (Economic Journal, June 2012) Vox Column
Exchange Rate
Crises and Fiscal Solvency (slides) (Journal
of Money, Credit, and Banking, September 2010)
The Fiscal Theory of
the Price Level and Initial Government Debt (Review of Economic Dynamics, April 2007)
It is widely believed that the Fiscal Theory of the Price Level (FTPL) does not work in an environment in which initial government debt is zero. This paper demonstrates that this view is incorrect when asset markets are incomplete and fiscal policy is stochastic. In particular, it is possible to define a stochastic non-Ricardian fiscal policy for which the set of equilibrium stochastic price processes under non-Ricardian fiscal policy is a subset of the set of equilibrium stochastic price processes under Ricardian fiscal policy.
Financial
Liberalization and Banking Crises in Emerging Economies co-authored with
John Jones (Journal of International
Economics, May 2007).
Financial liberalization often leads to financial crises. This link has usually been attributed to poorly designed banking systems, an explanation that is largely static. In this paper we develop a dynamic explanation, by modeling the evolution of a newly-liberalized bank's opportunities and incentives to take on risk over time. The model reveals that even if a banking system is well-designed, in the sense of having good long-run properties, many countries will enjoy an initial period of rapid, low-risk growth and then enter a period with an elevated risk of banking crisis. This transition emerges because of the way in which the degree of foreign competition, the marginal product of capital, and the bank's own net worth simultaneously evolve.